Foreword
to Professor
Reisman's
A
Free-Market Alternative"
Today’s conservatives
seem interested only in finding ways to conserve the regime they dub
“liberal” rather than ways to dismantle it. Unlike the old social
democrats who proposed market means to achieve socialist ends, today’s
conservatives promote statist means to achieve market ends. As much as
statist liberals venerate Lincoln, conservatives revere FDR. For
conservatives are equally democratic statists. Much of the upcoming
debate will revolve around a conservative effort to assuage liberal fear
that reform will jeopardize the very existence of a popular
redistribution scheme.
According to the
Bushi'ite scheme, tax revenue will continue to be collected, but the
taxed would be allowed to participate in the fine art of governmental
expenditure. That is, they will be allowed to direct a portion of
governmental revenue into private investment vehicles. This will
redound to the certain benefit of their trustees, but to the uncertain
benefit of the investor. What they will not be allowed to do is to put
any portion (let alone all) of their Social Security Withholding into
their checking or savings accounts and then spend, save, or truly invest
those funds as they see fit. They will continue to be forcibly
prevented from doing that because the Nanny State doesn’t trust them to
provide for their future. And the Republican conservative concurs.
There was a time when
no conservative worthy of the name regarded “social security,” or
“entitlement” programs, or taxpayer-funded “public” schools, or “civil
rights” with anything but horror. What he was trying to conserve was the
Old Republic. However one may assess that goal (the Old Republic had
already been drawn-and-quartered during the unsuccessful War for
Southern Independence), at least Old Rightists did not frame it in terms
of the values of its despisers.
I do
not wish to deprive self-styled conservatives of the pleasure of
mud-wrestling their liberal rivals in the pigpen of practical politics
(which gave us the Leviathan state). I understand if they do not wish
to peer between its slats to confront their destiny as bacon. I, too,
will "get my hands dirty," and if need be splintered, but only to rip
down those slats. As Mill put it, I’d rather be a human being
unsatisfied than a pig satisfied. Now I’m not classifying conservatives
and liberals as porcine, but their habit of mocking those who dream of
life outside the pen reminds me of the three little porkers’
underestimation of the wolf.
A sensible intellectual
division of labor suggests that philosophers, as such, need not spend
their time examining the shifting probabilities that
would govern the proposed accrual of Social Security benefits,
especially when experts like Professor Reisman have already done that
for us.
Anthony Flood
February 21, 2005
A Free-Market Alternative
Considerable public discussion and debate
now rages over Social Security and how to reform it. As the system
currently stands, as early as 2018, it will be necessary to finance a
growing portion of its outlays to retirees by means of outside sources of
funds, since at that point the sums paid into the system in the form of
payroll taxes will begin to fall short of the sums it is obligated to pay
out. What will bring this about is a substantial increase in the number of
retirees, who draw from the system, relative to the number of workers, who
pay into it.
Some observers believe that the
difficulties faced by the system will not begin until later, in 2042 or
2052. Between 2018 and that time, they believe, the system can draw down
its vast accumulations of United States Government securities, which it
has acquired over the many years in which it took in more in payroll taxes
than it has had to pay out.
I believe that 2018 is in fact the time
when the difficulties will begin. The reason is that the government
securities held by the Social Security system are not any kind of actual
asset. They are a claim against the US Government to pay money that it
does not possess and which it cannot obtain in any way other than by
raising taxes, borrowing from the public, or inflating the money supply.
Probably, just as has been the case many times since the system was
established seventy years ago, social security payroll taxes will be
increased one or more times again between now and 2018, and that will
provide the funds. In other words, the tax system of the United States
will come to resemble that of Sweden more than it does now.
Perhaps to avoid such further payroll tax
increases, President Bush has put forward his proposal to partially
“privatize” the system. According to the President's proposal, workers
below the age of 55 will be allowed to have a portion of their and their
employers' contributions to the system invested in stocks and corporate
bonds rather than in United States Government bonds. The presumably higher
rate of return they will earn thereby will supposedly reduce the need of
the government to rely on Social Security taxes in the future as the
source of meeting its pension obligations.
Unfortunately, implementing the
President's proposal entails trillions of additional dollars of government
borrowing or new taxes in the years before any reduced need for Social
Security taxes can materialize. This is because the funds being invested
in the so-called private accounts will largely be at the expense of funds
available to meet the system's pension obligations. Under the President's
proposal, as much as almost a third of the contributions made by the
eligible workers and their employers could be funneled into the stock
market and thus would not be available to pay current pensions. Since the
government is still obligated to pay those pensions, this shortfall can be
covered only by additional borrowing, new taxes, or inflation of the money
supply. As
Lew Rockwell
has pointed out, the President's proposal is thus actually one of a new
and additional government program rather than being the mere reform of an
existing program.
Another, and potentially more serious,
problem is that implementing the President's proposal would almost
certainly mean a major increase in the government's power over business.
Unless the government were prepared to give full freedom to the individual
to invest in any stocks of his choice, it would, as a minimum, have to
draw up a list of stocks that it approved for purchase. The result of this
would be that a very large number of publicly traded companies would be
under pressure to convince the government to add their stock to the list
and to keep it on the list. In order to do this, of course, a company, and
all the individuals prominently associated with it, would have to avoid
doing anything that might displease government officials and thereby lead
the government to shun the company's stock. Thus a major new avenue of
arbitrary government power would be opened up.
Almost certainly, however, the government
would not be content with merely drawing up a list of approved stocks and
then leave the choice of the specific stocks within the list, and the
timing of their purchase and sale, to the discretion of the individual
taxpayers. Doing so would contradict a major underlying premise of the
whole Social Security system. That premise is that the average person
cannot be relied upon to provide adequately for his old age even under
conditions in which all he would have to do is regularly deposit money in
a savings account at a bank or pay the premiums on an endowment-insurance
policy.
The truth, of course, is that the average
person, and the great majority of people even of substantially
below-average ability, certainly could do this much, provided that they
could take the future buying power of their savings for granted. But the
government long ago destroyed the gold standard, and the resulting chronic
inflation has left an enormous number of people in a situation in which
they really are unable to cope with the requirements of saving and
investing on their own. They are unable to cope precisely because
investing in the stock market has been left as practically the only viable
form of investment, since it at least offers hope of keeping up with the
rise in prices. Such people—tens of millions of them—do not possess the
necessary knowledge or, indeed, the necessary time, to seriously follow
the ever changing conditions of the stock market and of the individual
companies and industries whose shares are traded. Alleged concern for
these people must almost inevitably lead to the government taking full and
direct charge of any stock-market investments that might be made under the
auspices of the Social Security system.
The consequences of the government's
necessary control over such stock-market investments would be extremely
grave. It would mean that the government would come to control a
substantial portion of the stock of most major corporations in the United
States. As a further result, the government would come to appoint
members of the boards of directors of those corporations, in the same way
that other substantial stockholders do. Just imagine practically every
major business in the United States having one or more government members
on its board of directors! The distance between such an arrangement
and the government's management of the economic system—i.e., socialism—is
certainly not very great.
Amazingly, such obvious considerations
seem to have escaped the politicians, the news media, and even “Wall
Street,” which looks forward only to higher stock prices, more
commissions, and more investment-management fees if Social-Security funds
are invested in the stock market.
Social Security is in trouble. A reform
is needed. But not the one suggested by the President. What is needed is a
reform that reduces the role of government, not enlarges it.
Here is an alternative,
pro-free-market reform of Social Security that I suggest. It is one
that many readers will find extremely radical and perhaps frightening as
well. I put it forward in the hope that it will serve as a starting point
for further discussion leading to the achievement of the ultimate goal of
economic freedom.
First, following a period of two to three
years to allow time for necessary adjustments to be made, immediately
raise the Social Security retirement age from 66 (which it is scheduled to
be as of 2009) to 70.
This, of course, would be a major
disappointment to everyone who had counted on starting to receive a Social
Security pension sooner. Fortunately, there is a way to give these people
a substantial form of relief, which would go a long way toward alleviating
their hardship. That is, at the same time that sixty-six year olds are
denied entry into the Social Security system, enact for their benefit a
“senior citizens' employment-income tax exemption” in the amount of, say,
$90,000 per year, which is equal to the current maximum income subject to
the Social Security tax. The far greater part of the taxes thereby waived
for these seniors on their income derived from employment would be taxes
the government would never have collected in the first place, since most
of the seniors would not have been working otherwise. The elimination of
the government's payment of pensions to this group would far outweigh any
loss of revenue from those sixty-six year olds who would have worked and
paid taxes on their incomes even in the absence of the rise in the Social
Security retirement age.
This income-tax exemption should be
extended and enlarged year by year until it embraces everyone in the 66 to
69 year-old age group. And, of course, it should be progressively
increased from year to year to keep pace with rising prices and rising
wage rates. Indeed, it should eventually be extended to apply to everyone
66 years old or older. States with income taxes of their own should be
required to adopt the same tax exemption. In this way, the years remaining
in life past today's customary retirement age might become truly “golden
years” for millions of people, who at last would be freed of the burden of
income taxes on their earnings derived from employment.
The retirement age of 70 should be
retained perhaps for as long as fifteen years, to make it possible for all
workers aged 55 and over at the time of its enactment to take advantage of
it. Thereafter, however, the Social Security retirement age should be
gradually increased further, to 75, over, say, a twenty-year period,
rising at the rate of one calendar quarter for each passing year. Thus,
workers aged 54 at the time of the reform's enactment would be eligible
for social security at the age of 70 ¼, while those aged 35 at the time of
its enactment would not be eligible until the age of 75.
The Social Security system should accept
no new pension recipients after the end of this twenty year period. In
other words, it would be closed to workers 34 years of age and younger at
the time of the reform's enactment. These workers, who would be ineligible
for Social Security, would all have ample time to make their own provision
for the future. The Social Security system itself would progressively
decline and ultimately disappear as its pensioners passed away.
The government's very considerable
savings from reduced pension obligations over an initial phase-out period
totaling almost forty years from start to finish, should be earmarked for
reductions in the Social Security taxes of the workers who will never be
able to enter the system, i.e., in the above scenario, workers aged 34 and
less at the time of the reform's enactment. As these workers advance in
age, new workers will be entering the labor market. There will thus be an
increasing number of workers to bear the burden of the Social Security
system's final phase. This will permit Social Security tax rates to be
steadily reduced on this group, until they disappear altogether.
The end of Social Security would be the
end of something that should never have been started in the first place.
The root of the system is the philosophy of collectivism, in that it
forces everyone into a giant stewpot as it were, in which individuals are
compelled to support the parents and grandparents of total strangers,
whether they want to or not, in exchange for themselves later on being
compulsorily supported by the children and grandchildren of total
strangers.
And, of course, standing between the
generations has been a mass of politicians and government officials who
have used whatever excess has existed of these forced exactions over
current pension payments, to fund ordinary, current government spending.
If a private insurance or annuity company
had done such a thing and used its excess of premium income over current
payments, to finance the consumption of its owners and employees, for
whatever purpose, including the funding of charities and public works, the
company officials would now be spending long terms in prison. For it would
be very clear that they had embezzled the funds of their clients. Yet
exactly that in essence is what politicians and government officials have
done, on a scale far surpassing all private financial frauds combined over
the whole of human history.
But what is worse is that under a
collectivist system such as Social Security, such embezzlement is
preferable to its alternative, which would be government investment of the
funds and thus government control of much of the economic system, which
latter is where the President's proposal leads.
The end of Social Security and its
diversion of funds into government consumption—the return to private,
individual saving and provision for the future—will mean a great increase
in saving and the accumulation of capital, because the savings of
individuals will be invested, not squandered. This, in turn, will mean a
more prosperous and more rapidly progressing economic system, in which the
standard of living of everyone, young and old will greatly improve.
The only really proper reform of Social
Security is the gradual abolition of the whole system.
Professor of Economics at Pepperdine University's Graziadio School of
Business and Management in Los Angeles, George Reisman is the author of
Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics (Ottawa,
Illinois: Jameson Books, 1996) which, through the author's generosity, is
freely available online in .pdf format (all 1,100+ pages of it!). He is
also the translator of Ludwig von Mises's Epistemological Problems of
Economics (New York: D. Van Nostrand & Co., 1960). He also has a
firstrate
web site.
The article reproduced above is copyright © 2005, by George Reisman.
Permission is hereby granted to reproduce and distribute this article
electronically and in print, other than as part of a book. (Email
notification is requested). All other rights
reserved. The article incorporates portions of Dr. Reisman's previously
published
“Social Security Rescue Plans Mean Government Ownership of Business.”
Contact him and comment on this essay on the
blog at Mises.org.
The reader who benefits from Professor Reisman's article should also enjoy
Murray Rothbard’s popular
article on Social Security. Another
Misesian economist, Hans Sennholz, analyzes it
here, and
Lew Rockwell dissects Bush's "privatization" fiasco
in
"The Failed Compromise".