Chapter
Twenty-Nine of Western Technology and Soviet Economic Development,
1945-1965, Stanford, CA: Stanford University, Hoover Institution
Press, 1973, 411-423. The original title is “Conclusions.” This volume
is the third of three, but this chapter refers to all three.
“Although the policies concerning trade and technical transfers appear
vague and often confused, there is one fundamental observa-tion to be
made: throughout the period of 50 years from 1917 to 1970 there was a
persis-tent, powerful, and not clearly identifiable force in the West
making for continuance of the transfers. . . .”
“. . . whenever the Soviet economy has reached a crisis point, Western
governments have come to its assistance. . . . All along, the survival
of the Soviet Union has been in the hands of Western governments.”
In this study's closing pages, Sutton would admit only that he “lean[ed]
to the position that there is gross incompetence in the policymaking and
re-search sections of the State Department.” He would spend the rest of
his life attempting to clearly identify that force, thereby replacing
this earlier verdict of incompetence with a more satisfying one.
Anthony Flood
July 29, 2010
Western Technology and Soviet Economic Development: Conclusions
Antony C. Sutton
Empirical Conclusions: 1917 to 1930
The first volume of this
study concluded that the Soviets employed more than 350 foreign
concessions during the 1920s. These concessions, introduced into the
Soviet Union under Lenin’s New Economic Policy, enabled foreign
entrepreneurs to establish business operations in the Soviet Union
without gaining property rights. The Soviet intent was to introduce
foreign capital and skills, and the objective was to establish
concessions in all sectors of the economy and thereby introduce Western
techniques into the dormant post-revolutionary Russian economy. The
foreign entrepreneur hoped to make a normal business profit in these
operations.
Three types of
concessions were isolated: Type I, pure concessions; Type II, mixed
concessions; Type III, technical-assistance agreements. Information was
acquired on about 70 percent of those actually placed in operation. It
was found that concessions were employed within all sectors of the
economy except one (furniture and fittings), although the largest single
group of concessions was in raw materials development. In the Caucasus
oil fields—then seen as the key to economic recovery by virtue of the
foreign exchange that oil exports would generate—the International
Barnsdall Corporation introduced American rotary drilling techniques and
pumping technology. By the end of the 1920s 80 percent of Soviet oi
drilling was conducted by the American rotary technique; there had been
no rotary drilling at all in Russia at the time of the Revolution.
International Barnsdall also introduced a technical revolution in oil
pumping and electrification of oil fields. All refineries were built by
foreign corpora-tions, although only one, the Standard Oil lease at Batum, was under a concessionary arrangement—the remainder were built
under contract. Numerous Type I and Type III technical-assistance
concessions were granted in the coal, anthracite, and mining industries,
including the largest concession, that of Lena Goldfields, Ltd., which
operated some 13 distinct and widely separated industrial complexes by
the late 1920s. In sectors such as iron and steel, and particularly in
the machinery and electrical equip-ment manufacturing sectors, numerous
agreements were made between trusts and larger individual Tsa-rist-era
plants and Western companies to start up and reequip the plants with the
latest in Western technology, A.E.G., General Electric, and
Metro-politan-Vickers were the major operators in the ma-chinery sectors.
Only in the agricultural sector was the concession a failure.
After information had
been acquired on as many such concessions and technical-assistance
agree-ments as possible, the economy was divided into 44 sectors and the
impact of concessions and foreign technical assistance in each sector
was analyzed. It was found that about two-thirds of the sectors
received Type I and Type II concessions, while over four-fifths received
technical-assistance agreements with foreign companies. A summary
statement of this assistance, irrespective of the types of conces-sion,
revealed that all sectors except one, i.e., 43 sectors of a total of 44,
had received some form of concession agreement. In other words, in only
one sector was there no evidence of Western technolo-gical assistance
received at some point during the 1920s. The agreements were made
either with dominant trusts or with larger individual plants, but as
each sector at the outset comprised only a few large units bequeathed by
the Tsarist industrial structure, it was found that the skills
transferred were easily diffused within a sector and then supplemented
by imported equipment. Examination of reports by Western engineers
concerning individual plants confirmed that restarting after the
Revolution and technical progress during the decade were dependent on
Western assistance.
It was therefore
concluded that the technical transfer aspect of the New Economic Policy
was suc-cessful. It enabled foreign entrepreneurs and firms to enter the
Soviet Union. From a production of almost zero in 1922 there was a
recovery to pre-World War I production figures by 1928. There is no
question that the turn-around in Soviet economic fortunes in 1922 is to
be linked to German technical assistance, particularly that forthcoming
after the Treaty of Rapallo in April 1922 (although this assistance was
foreseeable as early as 1917 when the Germans financed the Revolution).
It was also determined
that the forerunners of Soviet trading companies abroad—i.e., the joint
trading firms—were largely established with the assistance of
sympathetic Western businessmen. After the initial contacts were made,
these joint trading firms disappeared, to be replaced by Soviet-operated
units such as Amtorg in the United States and Arcos in the United
Kingdom.
It was concluded that
for the period 1917 to 1930 Western assistance in various forms was the
single most important factor first in the sheer survival of the Soviet
regime and secondly in industrial progress to prerevolutionary levels.
Empirical Conclusions: 1930 to 1945
Most of the 350 foreign
concessions of the 1920s had been liquidated by 1930. Only those
entre-preneurs with political significance for the Soviets received
compensation, but for those few that did (for example, Hammer and
Harriman), the compen-sation was reasonable.
The concession was
replaced by the technical-assistance agreement, which together with
imports of foreign equipment and its subsequent standar-dization and
duplication, constituted the principal means of development during the
period 1930 to 1945.
The general design and
supervision of construc-tion, and much of the supply of equipment for the
gigantic plants built between 1929 and 1933 was provided by Albert Kahn,
Inc., of Detroit, the then most famous of U.S. industrial architectural
firm. No large unit of the construction program in those years was
without foreign technical assistance, and because Soviet machine tool
production then was limited to the most elementary types, all production
equipment in these plants was foreign. Soviet sources indicate that
300,000 high-quality foreign machine tools were imported between 1929
and 1940. These machine tools were supplemented by complete industrial
plants: for example, the Soviet Union received three tractor plants
(which also doubled as tank producers), two giant machine-building
plants (Kramatorsk and Uralmash), three major automobile plants,
numerous oil refining units, aircraft plants, and tube mills.
Published data on the
Soviet “Plans” neglect to mention a fundamental feature of the Soviet
indus-trial structure in this period: the giant units were built by
foreign companies at the very beginning of the 1930s, and the remainder
of the decade was devoted to bringing these giants into full production
and building satellite assembly and input-supply plants. In sectors
such as oil refining and aircraft, where further construction was
undertaken at the end of the decade, we find a dozen top U.S. companies
(McKee, Lummus, Universal Oil Products, etc.) aiding in the oil-refining
sector and other top U.S. aircraft builders in the aircraft sector
(Douglas, Vultee, Curtiss-Wright, etc.).
Only relatively
insignificant Soviet innovation occurred in this period: SK-B synthetic
rubber, dropped in favor of more useful foreign types after World War
II; the Ramzin once-through boiler, con-fined to small sizes; the turbodrill; and a few aircraft and machine gun designs.
The Nazi-Soviet pact and
Lend Lease ensured a continued flow of Western equipment up to 1945.
In sum, the Soviet
industrial structure in 1945 consisted of large units producing
uninterrupted runs of standardized models copied from foreign designs
and manufactured with foreign equipment. Where industrial equipment was
of elementary construction (e.g., roasters and furnaces in the chemical
industry, turret lathes in the machine tool industry, wooden aircraft,
and small ships), the Soviets in 1945 were able to take a foreign design
and move into produc-tion. One prominent example (covered in detail in
this volume) was the Caterpillar D-7 tractor. The original, sent under
Lend Lease in 1943, was copied in metric form and became the Soviet S-80
and S-100. It was then adapted for dozens of other military and
industrial uses.
Thus in the period 1930
to 1945 the Soviets generally no longer required foreign engineers as
operators inside the U.S.S.R. as they had in the concessions of the
1920s, but they still required foreign designs, foreign machines (the
machines to produce machines), and complete foreign plants in new
technical areas. By 1945 the Soviet Union had “caught up” at least
twice; once in the 1930s (it could also be argued that the assistance of
the 1920s constituted the first catching-up) with the construc-tion of
the First Five Year Plan by foreign companies, and again in 1945 as a
result of the massive flow of Western technology under Lend Lease.
While the technical skills demonstrated by the Tsarist craftsmen had
not quite been achieved,1 it may be said that in 1945 the
nucleus of a skilled engineering force was once again available in
Russia—for the first time since the Revolution.
Empirical Conclusions: 1945- 1965
In the immediate postwar
period the Soviets transferred a large proportion of German industry to
the Soviet Union—at least two-thirds of the German aircraft industry,
the major part of the rocket production industry, probably two-thirds of
the elec-trical industry, several automobile plants, several hundred
large ships, and specialized plants to pro-duce instruments, military
equipment, armaments, and weapons systems. The stripping of East
Germa-ny was supplemented by a U.S. program (Operation RAP) to give the
Soviets dismantled plants in the U.S. Zone. By the end of 1946 about 95
percent of dis-mantling in the U.S. Zone was for the U.S.S.R. (including
the aircraft plants of Daimler-Benz, ball bearings facilities, and
several munitions plants).
Manchuria and Rumania
also supplied numerous plants. And as we have seen, Finnish reparations
which supplemented the pulp and paper industries and ship construction
were made possible by U.S. Export-Import Bank credits to Finland.
In the late 1950s all
this industrial capacity had been absorbed and the Soviets turned their
attention to the deficient chemical, computer, shipbuilding, and
consumer industries, for which German acquisitions had been relatively
slight.2 A massive complete-plant purchasing program was
begun in the late 1950s—for example, the Soviets bought at least 50
complete chemical plants between 1959 and 1963 for chemicals not
previously produced in the U.S.S.R. A gigantic ship-purchasing program
was then instituted, so that by 1967 about two-thirds of the Soviet
merchant fleet had been built in the West. More difficulty was met in
the acquisition of computers and similar advanced technologies, but a
gradual weakening of Western export control under persistent Western
business and political pressures produced a situation by the end of the
sixties whereby the Soviets were able to purchase almost the very
largest and fastest of Western computers.
Soviet exports in the
late sixties were still those of a backward, underdeveloped country.
They con-sisted chiefly of raw materials and semi-manu-factured goods
such as manganese, chrome, furs, foodstuffs, pig iron, glass blocks, and
so on. When manufactured goods were exported they were simple machine
tools and vehicles based on Western designs, and they were exported to
underdeveloped areas. When foreign aid projects fell behind—al-though
they had been given first priority on Soviet resources—they were brought
back on schedule with the use of foreign equipment (e.g., British and
Swedish equipment was used at the Aswan Dam). And while great efforts
have been made to export to advanced Western markets Soviet goods with a
technological component (i.e., watches, auto-mobiles, tractors, and so
on), a technical breakdown of these goods reveals in all cases examined
either a Western origin or the substitution of Western parts where the
products are assembled in the West.3
As a further indicator
of Soviet technical back-wardness, it may be noted that some Western
firms selling to the Soviet Union have found “so many gaps in the
control schemes proposed”4 that a two-phase quotation format
has been adopted: first a feasibility study is conducted (for which the
Western company is paid), and then the actual quotation is determined
for a complete system based on the feasibility study. In other words,
technical inadequacy is such that the Soviets have not been able to
specify exactly what is wanted. What this reflects is not a lack of
scientific skill; it shows a lack of information on the technical
constituents of a modern industrial system.
In the few areas where
indigenous innovation was identified in the earlier period, we find a
move back toward the use of Western technology. This is visible in the
use of Western synthetic rubbers to replace SK-B, a renewed research
effort on rotary drilling as a result of efficiency problems encountered
in the use of the Soviet turbodrill, and instances of aban-donment of the Ramzin boiler in favor of Western designs. The research and development
effort has continued, but its results in practical engineering terms
have been near zero. From the technical viewpoint the Soviet Union at
1970 is a copy—a rather imperfect copy—of the West. Generally, initial
units are still built by Western companies and subsequent units built by
Soviet engineers are based on the original Western model, and imported
equipment is used in key process and control areas.
Original Western Intent for Technical Transfer
It may be unwise to
attempt to read into an his-torical sequence of events as important as
those described, any rational objective on the part of Wes-tern
statesmen. Although the policies concerning trade and technical
transfers appear vague and often confused, there is one fundamental
observation to be made: throughout the period of 50 years from 1917 to
1970 there was a persistent, powerful, and not clearly identifiable
force in the West making for continuance of the transfers. Surely the
political power and influence of the Soviets was not sufficient alone to
bring about such favorable Western policies. Indeed, in view of the
aggressive nature of declared Soviet world objectives, such policies
seem incom-prehensible if the West’s objective is to survive as an
alliance of independent, non-communist nations. What, then, are the
wellsprings of this phenomenon?
In the years 1917-20 a
variant of the modern “bridge-building” argument was influential within
policymaking circles. The Bolsheviks were outlaws, so the argument
went, and had to be brought into the civilized world. For example, in
1918 a statement by Edwin Gay, a member of the U.S. War Trade Board and
former Dean of the Harvard Business School, was paraphrased in the board
minutes as follows:
Mr. Gay stated the opinion that it was doubtful whether the policy of
blockade and economic isolation of these portions of Russia which were
under Bolshevik control was the best policy for bringing about the
establishment of a stable and proper Government in Russia. Mr. Gay
suggested to the [War Trade] Board that if the people in the Bolshevik
sections of Russia were given the opportunity to enjoy improved economic
conditions, they would themselves bring about the establishment of a
moderate and stable social order.5
At about the same time
American businessmen were instrumental in aiding the formation of the
Soviet Bureau, and several hundred firms had their names on file in the
bureau when it was raided in 1918.6 Hence there was Western
business pressure through political channels to establish Soviet trade.
No one appears to have foreseen the possibility of creating a powerful
and threatening enemy to the Free World. There was widespread criticism
of the Bolsheviks, but this was not allowed to interfere with trade. In
sum, there was no argument made against technical transfers while
several influential political and business forces were working actively
to open up trade.
The lack of clear policy
formulation and foresight was compounded by the apparent efforts of some
State Department officials in the 1930s to discourage collection of
information on Soviet economic actions and problems. While the First
Five Year Plan was under construction by Western companies, various
internal State Department memoranda disputed the wisdom of collecting
information on this construc-tion.7 For example, a detailed
report from the U.S. Embassy in Tokyo in 1933 (a report containing
precisely the kind of information used in this study) was described in
Washington as “not of great interest.”8 It is therefore
possible that no concerted effort to examine the roots of Soviet
industrial development has ever been made within the U.S. State
Department. Certainly internal State Depart-ment reports of the 1930s
provide less information than the present study was able to develop.
Such lack of ordered information would go far to account for many of
the remarkably inaccurate statements made to Congress by officials of
the State Department and its consultants in the 1950s and
1960s—statements sometimes so far removed from fact they might have been
drawn from the pages of Alice in Wonderland rather than the
testimony of senior U.S. Executive Department personnel and prominent
academicians.9
In brief, a possibility
exists that there has been no real and pervasive knowledge of these
technical transfers—even at the most “informed” levels of Western
governments. Further, it has to be hypothe-sized that the training of
Western government officials is woefully deficient in the area of
technology and development of economic systems, and that researchers
have been either unable to visualize the possibility of Soviet technical
dependence or unwil-ling, by reason of the bureaucratic aversion to
“rocking the boat,” to put forward research proposals to examine that
possibility. This does not however explain why some of the outside
consultants who were hired by all Western governments in such profusion,
have not systematically explored the possibility.10 If it is
argued, on the contrary, that Western Governments are aware of Soviet
technical dependency, then how does one explain the national security
problem, outlined in chapter 27?
An argument has been
made that a policy of technical assistance to the U.S.S.R. before World
War II was correct as it enabled the Soviets to withstand Hitler’s
attack of June 1941. This is ex post facto reasoning. The
German Government financed the Bolshevik Revolution with the aim of
removing an enemy (Tsarist Russia), but also with postwar trade and
influence in mind. This German support was largely replaced in the late
1920s by American technical assistance, but until the mid-1930s the
Germans were still arming the Soviets; it was only in 1939 that Hermann
Goering began to protest the supply. Thus in the twenties and the early
thirties it was not possible for anyone to foresee that Germany would
attack the Soviet Union.
The Bolsheviks were
assisted to power by a single Western government, Germany, and were
main-tained in power by all major Western governments. The result is
that we have created and continue to maintain what appears to be a
first-order threat to the survival of Western civilization. This was
done because in the West the political pressures for trade were stronger
than any countervailing argument.
This conclusion is
supported by the observations that in both the 1930s and the 1960s the
U.S. State Department pressed for the outright transfer of military
technology to the U.S.S.R. over the protests of the War Department (in
the thirties) and the Department of Defense (in the sixties). When in
the 1930s the War Department pointed out that the proposed Dupont nitric
acid plant had military potential, it was the State Department that
allowed the Dupont contract to go ahead.11 A Hercules Powder
proposal to build a nitrocellulose plant was approved when the State
Department accepted the argument that the explosives produced were
intended for peacetime use.12
In the 1960s we have the
extraordinary “ball bearing case” of 1961, which revealed that the
U.S.S.R. was to receive 45 machines used to produce miniature ball
bearings (in the United States almost all miniature ball bearings are
used in missiles). That proposal was called a “tragic mistake” by the
Department of Defense but supported by the State Department. In 1968
came the so-called “Fiat deal” under which the United States supplied
three-quarters of the equipment for the Volgograd plant, the largest
automobile plant in the U.S.S.R. This agreement ignored an earlier
interagency committee finding that 330 military items can be produced by
any civilian automobile industry and that the automobile industry is a
key factor for war. It also ignores an argument particularly stressed
here—that that any automobile plant can produce military vehicles. The
supply of U.S. equipment for the Volgo-gradplant was diametrically
opposed to any policy of denial of exports of strategic goods to the
Soviet Union, for under any definition of “strategic” the Volgograd
plant has clear and significant military weapons capability. Yet the
State Department was strongly in favor of the shipment of the plant
equipment. The developing story of the Kama plant suggests history is
repeating itself.
Under these conditions,
where policy is so far re-moved from logical deduction, it would be
imprudent to arrive at any conclusion concerning Western intentions. If
logical intentions exist—and in chapter 27 it is suggested that our
strategic policies are not logically derivable from observable fact—they
are obscure indeed. The writer leans to the position that there is
gross incompetence in the policymaking and research sections of the
State Department. There is probably no simple, logical explanation for
the fact that we have constructed and maintain a first-order threat to
Western society.
Implications for the Soviet Union
The Soviet Union has a
fundamental problem. In blunt terms, the Soviet economy, centrally
planned under the guidance of the Communist Party, does not constitute a
viable economic system. The system cannot develop technically across a
broad front with-out outside assistance; internal industrial capacity can
be expanded only in those sectors suitable for scaling-up innovation and
duplication of foreign techniques.
Quite clearly a modern
economy cannot be self-maintained, however skilled its planners and
technicians, if technical adoptions in basic industries are limited to
processes that lend themselves to scaling up or duplication. Further,
the more developed the economy the greater its complexity; consequently
the planning problems associated with the acquisition of information
must surely increase in geometric ratio.
Logically, then, a
system that is strictly centrally planned is not efficient either for
rapid balanced growth or for any growth at all once the economy is past
the primitive stage. Beyond that stage, the chief function of central
planning, so far as the economy is concerned, becomes the retention of
political control with the ruling group. There are few economic
functions, and certainly no technical functions, that cannot be
performed in a more efficient manner by a market economy.
How have the Russian
Party member, the Politburo, Stalin, Khrushchev, and Brezhnev looked
upon Western technology in relation to Soviet technology? This is
indeed a fascinating question. Party injunctions, for example in
Pravda, suggest that on many levels there has been a deep and
continuing concern with lagging Soviet technology. The general problem
has long been recognized, ever since Lenin’s time. But Lenin thought it
curable13; the current Politburo must at least suspect it is
incurable.
It is however unlikely
that either the Party in Russia or the Communist parties in the West
have fully probed the depths of the problem. First, their writings
mirror a persistent confusion between science and technology, between
invention and innovation.14 Second, it is unlikely that most
Marxists appreciate how important an indigenous innovative process is to
a nation’s self-sufficiency (in contrast to their clear understanding of
the value of scientific endeavor and invention). Even breakaways from
Marxist dogma still find it difficult to absorb the notion that
virtually all widely applied (i.e., innovated) technology in the Soviet
Union today may have originated in the outside world. Third, Russian
designers and engineers may have succeeded in deceiving the Party and
even themselves. By claiming as indigenous Russian work designs which
in fact originated in the West, they may have obscured the realities of
Soviet technology.
The dilemma facing the
Soviets in 1970 is stark and overwhelming, and periodic reorganization
and adjustments have not identified the basic cause. Indeed, each
reorganization either stops short of the point where it may have lasting
effect or leads to yet further problems. This is because the Party
con-tinues to demand absolute political control while a viable economy
increasingly demands the adapta-bility, the originality, and the
motivation that result from individual responsibility and initiative. Attemp-ted solutions through use of computers may tempo-rarily ease the
problem, but ultimately they too will result in confusion because
accurate information still has to be acquired and analyzed. The
computer is only as useful as its human operators are capable and as its
data input is sound. In any event, who will supply the computers?
Moreover a communist
regime cannot yield political power; doctrine demands continuance
of power in the hands of the Party. The economy demands diffusion of
power. What will be the result? If Russian historical precedent is any
indicator, then the outlook is gloomy indeed. The Russian Revolution
was a gigantic and violent upheaval. The first revolution achieved what
had been attained by evolutionary means elsewhere, the substitution of
relatively democratic control for autocracy. Then the briefly emergent
democratic forces in Russia were caught between the autocracy of the
right and the Bolsheviks of the left and were rendered impotent. A new
absolutism took power. Today there is no question that a fundamental
change has to come again; what is unknown is the form that change will
take and whether it will be revolutionary or evolutionary.
It is also clear—and the
writer makes this assertion only after considerable contemplation of the
evidence—that whenever the Soviet economy has reached a crisis point,
Western governments have come to its assistance. The financing of the
Bolshevik Revolution by the German Foreign Ministry was followed by
German assistance out of the abysmal trough of 1922. Examples of
continuing Western assistance include the means to build the First Five
Year Plan and the models for subsequent duplication; Nazi assistance in
1939-41 and U.S. assistance in 1941-45; the decline in export control in
the fifties and sixties; and finally the French, German, and Italian
credits of the sixties and the abandon-ment of controls over the shipment
of advanced technology by the United States in 1969. All along, the
survival of the Soviet Union has been in the hands of Western
governments. History will record whether they made the correct
decisions.
Implications for the Soviet Union
The Western business
firm has been the main vehicle for the transfer process, and individual
firms have, of course, an individual right to accept or reject Soviet
business in response to their own estimation of the profitability of
such sales. There is ample evidence in the files of the U.S. State
Department, the German Foreign Ministry, and the British Foreign Office
that Western firms have cooperated closely with their respective
governments in negotiating for such sales.
Historically, sales to
the Soviet Union must have been profitable, although the Russians are
reputed to be hard bargainers and there have been numerous examples of
bad faith and breaches of contract. Firms have accepted theft of
blueprints and specifications,15 duplication of their
equipment with-out permission or royalties,16 and similar
unethical practices and still deemed it worthwhile to continue trade.
This applies particularly to larger firms such as General Electric,
Radio Corporation of America, Ford Motor, Union Carbide, and Imperial
Chemical Industries, Ltd. There is evidence that larger firms are able
to demand and obtain somewhat more equitable treatment from the Soviets,
partly by virtue of the fact that respective foreign offices are more
willing to back them up and partly because the Soviets are aware of the
relatively few sources for their new technologies. But less well-known
firms such as Lummus, Universal Oil Products, and Vickers-Armstrongs
(Engineers), Ltd., apparently also have found that Soviet business pays.
This profitability must
be balanced against possi-ble loss of domestic sales in the face of
hostile do-mestic publicity. American Motors found itself in this trap
in 1966, when it had no more than vaguely con-templated sales to the
U.S.S.R.17—and other firms have suffered boycotts. As long
as these sales and the impact of such sales on Soviet capabilities were
relatively unknown, however, the possibility of boy-cotts was not great.
It appears that some reevalua-tion may be in order in the light of the
findings of this study; i.e., the factors entering into the tradeoffs in
considering such business may change. This applies certainly to sales
to Red China, where we now stand at a point equivalent to about 1921-22
with the Soviet Union. It is eminently clear that comparable sales over
a period of 50 years could place Red China on an equal industrial
footing with the U.S.S.R. The difference between the early seventies
and the early twenties is that we now have the example of the U.S.S.R.
before us: trade has built a formidable enemy, while hopes for a change
in ideology and objectives not only have gone unfulfilled but are
perhaps more distant than they were 50 years ago.
Implications for the Soviet Union
The Soviet problem is
not that the nation lacks theoretical or research capability18
or inventive genius. The problem is rather that there is a basic
weakness in engineering skills, and the system’s mechanisms for
generating innovation are almost nonexistent.
Table 29-1 [not
reproduced here.—A.F.] suggests the sparseness of Soviet innovation;
engineering weaknesses are implicit in continuing plant purchases
abroad—while such purchases continue the Soviets are not building plants
using their own laboratory discoveries. Why does the Soviet system have
such weaknesses?
There is certainly no
choice among competing inventions using market criteria, but if more
useful Soviet processes existed they would be adopted whether
market-tested or not. Absence of the marketplace is not, then,
sufficient reason to explain the absence of innovation. There may be,
as has been suggested elsewhere, no compelling pressures to develop
innovation despite the fact that the Party is constantly exhorting
technical progress. But the explanation that most adequately covers the
problem is one that has been previously mentioned though not heretofore
stressed-the “inability hypothesis.” The spectrum of engineering skills
required to build a complete polyester plant, a large truck plant, a
fast large-capacity computer, and a modern marine diesel engine just
does not exist in the Soviet Union. Sufficient engineering skills do
exist for limited objectives—a military structure can be organized to
select and marshal the technology of war, or a space program can be
decreed and realized through top-priority assignment of resources. But
the skills are not present to promote and maintain a complex,
self-regenerative industrial structure.
The point to be stressed
is that if there were adequate engineering ability some innovation would
be forthcoming in the form of original new processes, and such
innovation would appear in many sectors of the economy. This is
generally not the case. In most sectors the West installs the initial
plants and subsequent plants are duplicates based on that Western
technology. Once the sector has been esta-blished, major new innovations
within the sector tend to be either imported technologies or duplicates
of imported technologies. Therefore pervasive “inabili-ty” in
engineering seems the most likely basic expla-nation. For some
reason—and this study has not explored the diverse institutional factors
within the system that might be responsible—Soviet central planning has
not fostered an engineering capability to develop modern technologies
from scratch, nor has it generated inputs (educational, motivational,
and material) to achieve this objective.
The world is now
presented with 50 years’ history of industrial development in the most
important of socialist experiments, and censorship can no longer hide
the problem. Every new Soviet purchase of a major Western technology is
pari passu evidence for a central lesson of this study: Soviet
central planning is the Soviet Achilles’ heel.
Notes
1
Tsarist-era technology was of a higher standard than is generally
believed: it had achieved capability to produce aircraft, calculating
machines, and loco-motives. Foss Collection, Hoover Institution; see
Sutton [Western Technology and Soviet Economic Development], I,
pp. 183-84.
2
For typical articles that appeared in Western journals as the Soviets
took steps to start a massive acquisition program to fill major
technical gaps in the Soviet structure, see: Raymond Ewell, “Soviet
Russia Poses a New Industrial Threat,” ASTM Bulletin, no. 239
(July 1959), 43-44; W. Benton, “Are We Losing the Sheepskin War,”
Democratic Digest, July 1956; “From Revolution to Automation in 37
Years,” American Machinist, November 19, 1956; G. Marceau,
“Exceptionnelles possibilites du forage en U.R.S.S.,” Industrie du
petrole, 28 (November 1960), 47-49; “Soviet Scientists Emerge from
Curtain to Crow about Progress,” Business Week, September 14,
1957, pp. 30-32.
3
For the example of watches, see Business Week, June 6, 1960, p.
74.
4
Control Engineering (New York), November 1958, p. 80.
5
Minutes of the U.S. War Trade Board, December 5, 1918, vol. V, pp.
43-44.
6
New York [State] Legislature, Joint Legislative Committee to Investigate
Seditious Activities (Lusk Committee), Albany, N.Y., 1919.
7
See U.S. State Dept. Decimal File, 861.50/Five Year Plan/50.
8
U.S. State Dept. Decimal File, 861.5017/Living Conditions/709, Report
no. 689, Tokyo, August 31, 1933.
9
A former assistant chief of the division of research of the Department
of State has formed equally harsh conclusions. Bryton Barron has listed
four examples of highly strategic tools whose export to the U.S.S.R. was
urged by officials of the Department of State:
“1. Boring mills essential to the manufac-ture of tanks, artillery,
aircraft, and for the atomic reactors used in submarines.
“2. Vertical boring mills essential to the manufacture of jet engines.
“3. Dynamic balance machines used for balancing shafts on engines for
jet airplanes and guided missiles.
“4. External cylindrical grinding machines which a Defense Department
expert testi-fied are essential in making engine parts, guided missiles,
and radar.”
Barron concludes: “It should be evident that we cannot trust the
personnel of the Department to apply our agreements in the nation’s
interests any more than we can trust it to give us the full facts about
our treaties and other international commit-ments.” See Bryton Barron,
Inside the State Depart-ment (New York: Comet Press, 1956).
10
See p. x.
11
See Sutton, Western Technology . . . 1930 to 1945, p. 101.
12
Ibid., p. 113.
13
V. I. Lenin, Selected Works. J. Fineberg, ed., vol. IX (New York,
International Publishers, 1937), pp. 116.118.
14
Another and more puzzling facet of the Soviet concept of what begets
innovation is found in descriptions of the innovatory process in
practice. For example, an article by G. B. Nagigin on innovation in the
glass industry states: “Technical offices were established [in one
factory] before the start of the competition. Leading engineers and
technologists were on duty in these offices and gave practical
assistance to innovators who turned to them for advice, consultation,
etc. The technical offices are equipped with reference literature and
other material needed by innovators and inventors. For example, there
is a drawing board and the necessary instru-ments in the technical office
of the Gushkovskii Works. The establishment of well-equipped technical
offices, with qualified engineers on duty, naturally had a very
favorable effect on the development of innovation and invention work in
the factories.” Steklo i keramika (New York), vol. XIV, no. 2. p.
66. A table is included in the article giving “results.” We have to
assume that this scheme to encourage com-petition was a serious attempt
to induce the inno-vatory process—although one is tempted to dismiss it
as naive in the extreme. It need only be said that anyone with the
slightest knowledge of invention and innovation would conclude that
little that is worthwhile can be achieved by such a forced and
artificial process.
15
Sutton II, pp. 263-67.
16
Ibid.
17
See Milwaukee Journal, January 22, 1967.
18
For example of Russian research capability see A. V. Zolotov,
Problema tungusskoi katasstrofy 1908 g. (Minsk, 1969). a fascinating
empirical study of vari-ous hypotheses relating to the gigantic meteorite
that fell in Siberia in 1908.